A_map_of_New_England,_being_the_first_that_ever_was_here_cut_..._places_(2675732378).jpg
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Mike Rispoli: Creating new local constituencies for news

There’s a crisis in journalism. Rapidly changing consumer habits have slashed demand for the print editions of newspapers and magazines, squeezed advertising dollars, and made thousands of media jobs vanish.

The news industry’s downturn has created another crisis: People across the country are finding it harder to get the information they need to participate in society and be engaged members of their communities.

The public loses the most when local news coverage disappears. According to the latestcensus from the American Society of Newspaper Editors, newsroom employment dropped by more than 10 percent in 2014 alone. And over the last 10 years, the number of newsroom jobs has plummeted 39 percent.

Each of those lost jobs means one fewer journalist representing the public interest and holding the powerful accountable.

There’s often a real distance between journalists and the communities they’re supposed to serve. To make local reporting more viable and vibrant, it needs to consider perspectives from outside the news industry. That’s why Free Press started News Voices. Our new project will connect newsrooms and communities and build a collaborative network of people invested in local journalism.

There’s no better place to experiment on ways to create this network than New Jersey, one of the most underserved states when it comes to local media coverage.

When Free Press surveyed Garden State residents about their local media, many noted that they craved more coverage of their communities. A significant share of the state’s 565 municipalities lacks a locally rooted news outlet. Many of the outlets that do exist ignore residents’ concerns.

Almost all survey respondents remarked on how the location of New Jersey — sandwiched as it is between the huge media markets of Philadelphia and New York City — means that important local issues often fail to get sufficient coverage.

“The past two decades have seen local newspapers bought out and either closed down, absorbed, or just hanging on with little local coverage,” said a survey respondent from Rumson, a New Jersey suburb. These papers are “merely a shadow of the past when each municipality was well covered.”

This isn’t an indictment of the media in New Jersey. Every U.S. newsroom is under pressure to do more with less, and delivering that extra load in a 24-hour news cycle can come at the expense of quality public-service journalism. Another loss: the capacity to cultivate the sources journalists need to cover vital local stories.

Local journalism is at its best when it’s community-driven. The News Voices project is about listening to what New Jersey residents have to say about their information needs — and bringing journalists to the table to hear those voices. By teaming up with reporters, members of the public can advocate for the kind of reliable, credible, and timely information they require.

We aim to create something that doesn’t yet exist: a constituency for the news. And by that I mean a constituency that not only consumes the news but also advocates for its future.

Mike Rispoli is the press freedom campaign director for Free Press (FreePress.net). This piece originated at OtherWords.org.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Seeing ourselves in a mushroom

Peterson  

"Skinny White'' (HD C-print), by DAN PETERSON, in the show "Multiple Perspectives,'' at Adelson Galleries, Boston, Sept. 12-Oct. 11.

Mr. Peterson like to express abstract ideas through organic shapes like those of the mushrooms he finds in the Berkshires.

As the gallery notes say:

"These small organisms that inhabit the forest floor are hardly visible among the dense timbers and leaves, yet when spotted, they pop with rebellious hues.  The artist finds the most beautiful specimens along his daily walks, then isolates, photographs, and enhances them to a human-scale – allowing viewers to admire their microscopic intricacies.  The artist feels that we are connected to these beautiful organic shapes, and cannot help but see ourselves in their forms.''

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Chris Powell: Too late to stop the bad Iran deal

Connecticut isn't convulsed as Washington is over President Obama's nuclear inspections agreement with Iran. All members of the state's congressional delegation, all Democrats, have endorsed the agreement except Sen. Richard Blumenthal, who hasn't decided yet, and they wouldn't be supporting it if their constituents were furious about it. Nevertheless, last week U.S. Rep. John B. Larson (D-1st District), held a forum in his district with a State Department official who helped negotiate the agreement, Chris Backemeyer, the department's deputy coordinator for sanctions policy. Backemeyer answered critical questions from a well-informed crowd of about 80 people who, if not entirely convinced, hurled no tomatoes and appreciated that their concerns were taken seriously. Ready to keep taking punches, Backemeyer and Larson met afterward with several journalists.

While Iran may delay by a few weeks the access of international inspectors to any new suspected nuclear development sites, Backemeyer and Larson said radiation leaves enough traces that any cheating at such sites will be caught quickly.

They added that the release of $150 billion in frozen Iranian assets won't be as big a bonanza to Iran's international terrorism and subversion as many fear, since Iran will need to reserve much of the money to manage its international trade.

But Iran already is said to be within a few months of capability to build nuclear bombs, and if the country is determined to get them, the agreement and inspections won't delay it much. If Iran is found to be cheating, presumably the nations that were enforcing economic sanctions against Iran will reimpose them, but Iran will have regained its frozen assets and put them to use for terror and subversion, particularly against the United States and its ally Israel.

This seems to be what most distresses Americans about the agreement with Iran -- that it is not a peace treaty but actually will help Iran continue its de-facto wars against fellow members of the United Nations. Thus it is silly to believe that Iran really wants to comply with the agreement or that it will comply with it for long.

The world should have continued blockading Iran economically without exchanging sanctions for an agreement about nuclear weapons, as the blockade was causing great political discontent among Iranians and weakening their government, a fascist theocracy led by a fuhrer who claims to be implementing the will of God. Continuing the economic blockade would have been more likely to change Iran's behavior and perhaps even its regime than the agreement is likely to prevent Iran from making nuclear weapons.

But it's too late now and nothing would be gained by Congress's rejection of the agreement. President Obama induced this country's allies to put great effort into negotiating the agreement and they will not humiliate themselves in front of their own people and the world by reversing their position now because the president did not first build a consensus in Congress for his policy.

Without proof of Iran's violating the agreement, any attempt by the United States to reimpose sanctions on Iran would not have enough international support to be effective. Instead of isolating Iran, the United States would be isolating itself and breaking up the alliance against Iran, such as it is. There would be neither an economic blockade nor nuclear inspections.

The agreement with Iran is largely appeasement. But appeasement is increasingly the attitude in Europe, and while polls say Americans oppose the agreement, they are not likely to support another military adventure in the Middle East, the adventures in Afghanistan and Iraq having turned out so badly.

There's not much left for the United States to do here but regroup its allies to contain Iran, starting by giving Israel, Jordan, and Saudi Arabia what they need to defend themselves.

Chris Powell is managing editor of the Journal Inquirer, in Manchester, Conn.

 

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Thomas M. Paine: Save Boston Children's Hospital's healing garden

  garden

The Prouty Garden, at Boston Children's Hospital.

-- photo by Thomas M. Paine

For almost 60 years Boston Children’s Hospital considered the acclaimed Prouty Garden an integral part of its mission. The garden’s donor, longtime hospital trustee Olive Higgins Prouty, who had lost two young daughters, had the word of then-President William Wolbach that the garden she was endowing in 1956 would  remain forever.  That commitment is about to end unless the board quickly rethinks its plan to demolish the garden in a proposed $1.2 billion project to overhaul the hospital’s neonatal intensive-care unit and replace 82 semi-private rooms with single rooms with showers and clothing storage.

From its creation, Prouty Garden has been a sanctuary of healing where children confined for long periods can brighten their stays and hasten their recovery with daily visits to smell the flowers, discover the hidden statues, or see themselves reflected in the fountain pool. The expansive lawns, majestic dawn redwood, shrubs and perennial borders have provided respite for countless distraught families, visitors and overworked hospital personnel. Many children have spent their last moments on earth in the peace of Prouty Garden. It is where President John F. Kennedy came to grieve after the loss of his newborn son, Patrick Bouvier Kennedy. Originally designed by the famed Olmsted Brothers firm, Prouty Garden is “one of the most successful hospital gardens in the country,” according to healing-gardens authority Clare Cooper Marcus.

Prouty Garden advocates maintain that, frustrated with delay and wary of ballooning costs, the board has rejected some 17 plans that would preserve Prouty Garden. All 17 apparently had “fatal flaws.” The chosen plan was the only one considered that sacrifices Prouty Garden. Such decisions are never easy, and precisely what factors informed the decision process are not public. The board apparently, and no doubt reluctantly, concluded that Prouty Garden is not an inviolable part of the hospital’s mission but rather a temporary, expendable amenity.

To compensate for the loss, the selected design includes other landscaping. The renderings available online show a ground-level courtyard crisscrossed by walkways separated by raised planters of bamboos underplanted with groundcover. There are pocket parks in upper floors of the 11-story building, and a green roof. But does that settle the matter?

The fragmented greenspace in the preferred plan cannot compare with the expansive 23,000-square-foot Prouty Garden, with its spacious lawn under open skies, on firm ground, away from busy walkways, where kids can roam and families can find solitude. Even the largest green space in the design, the proposed outdoor courtyard, offers none of that immersive power, and the small pocket gardens on the upper levels can do even less. A green roof would hardly offer calm and security, let alone be planted with large trees or be visible from a hospital window. As to where families  would go to grieve alone, or terminally ill children  would spend their last moments, the proposed spaces are no substitute for Prouty Garden.

Board members have rightly emphasized the needs of the children over the needs of the hospital. But have they adequately considered how the garden itself serves children’s needs?  Environmental psychologist Roger Ulrich demonstrates that experiencing nature in a hospital garden even for five minutes can speed healing significantly, that hospital gardens are especially effective for calming stressed patients, family members, and staff, and that patient exposure to nature reduces health-care costs.[i]

But scientific facts don’t tell the whole story. The personal testimonials posted at saveprouty.org offer compelling evidence of the difference that Prouty Garden has made. Shelley Senai tells what happened after her daughter Juniper was born with protruding bowels: “All told, we spent 101 days living at your hospital during the summer of 2013 and I can’t think of a day that we didn’t spend in the garden, unless it was raining….We met other parents there and got a feel for the community that was happening in this big hospital around us.” Caitlyn O’Hara, a lifelong cystic fibrosis patient who has relied on Prouty Garden for three decades and is waiting for a lung transplant, says pocket gardens and roof gardens do not compare: “A manufactured rooftop garden, no matter how lovely, cannot replace the magic of the natural world.”

More than 11,000 patients, families, staff, donors and community members have signed a change.org petition to preserve Prouty Garden. While they recognize the need for the proposed new hospital facilities, they argue that the garden, which is no less essential to its patients, patient families, nurses,  physicians and other medical personnel, can and should be saved. Prouty Garden advocates are raising funds to press their case in ways that the board cannot ignore.

In New York City, trustees of the Frick Collection, a private art museum, recently decided to rethink expansion plans that would have eliminated the museum’s beloved garden for needed building space. If people were up in arms about the loss of a museum garden, how much more compelling and deep are the feelings evoked by the imminent loss of a hospital garden for sick and ill children.

I urge the hospital administration to declare a moratorium and go back to the drawing board. Surely, talented architects can produce a plan that avoids substantially altering the outdoor space that has been indispensable for the past six decades. Prouty Garden, which was intended to last forever, is about to be lost forever, unless the board changes course.

Thomas M. Paine, a landscape architect, is the author of Cities with Heart, about the importance of public open space. In 1976, he designed a corner of the Prouty Garden when he was an associate at Shurcliff, Merrill & Footit. He was a patient at the hospital in 1952.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

A summer place

starboardlight  

 

This is a lovely documentary by Nick Fitzhugh about a lost family summer place in Chatham, on Cape Cod.

It will be broadcast again on Rhode Island PBS, at 8 p.m. Sept. 24.

The film will evoke much nostalgia  in many New Englanders.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

David Warsh: Global economy zigs, macro-economics zags

“A small cloud, no bigger than a man’s hand…” 

The prophet Elijah’s most famous forecast (I Kings 18:44) – the sudden storm, deduced from inconspicuous change, that ended a three-year drought – became a cliché in business journalism in the 1970s, as one industry after another was overtaken by rapid change that it hadn’t anticipated.

There were no such metaphors in economics – an outgrowth of the conviction summed up by Alfred Marshall’s motto, Natura non facit saltum – Nature makes no leaps. For economists educated in marginalism and the differential calculus, it was an entirely natural way of thinking of the world.

Thus the news from China barely made a dent in the U.S.  in 1976. The Cultural Revolution was said to be winding down. Zhou Enlai died in February; an earthquake in Tangshan in July killed as many as 650,000 people; Mao Zedong died in September. The Mandate of Heaven, an ancient governing concept in Chinese civilization, had, it was said, perhaps been lost. Americans were preoccupied with recovery from a recession, a presidential election, the bicentennial celebration of their Declaration of Independence;, Europeans with their record-breaking hot summer.

Barely two years later, the Communique of the Third Plenum of the Eleventh Central Committee announced a plan to “shift the emphasis of our party’s work and the attention of the people of the whole country to socialist modernization.” People’s material lives must be improved, it declared; bureaucratic self-indulgence would not be tolerated. A “new Long March” would make China “a great modern socialist power” by the end of the twentieth century.

Six months later a highly promising  Republic of China (Taiwanese) army captain named Justin Zhengyi Lin slipped out of his uniform on the island of Quemoy in the middle of the night and swam a mile to the mainland port of Xiamin. Reunification was both inevitable and desirable, Lin had concluded and, as one of Taiwan’s most celebrated young citizens, he wanted to express his conviction as dramatically as possible, leaving behind a large family whom he loved.

It took the mainland authorities a little while to assess his motives – was he a double-agent? He wasn’t. By 1980, calling himself Yifu Lin (“Persistent man on a long journey”), he was studying political economy at Beijing University. Assigned to translate that spring for visiting Nobel laureate Theodore Schultz, Lin impressed the visitor.

By 1982, on a scholarship arranged by Schultz and approved by the authorities in Beijing, he was pursuing a Ph.D. at the University of Chicago. And 25  years after that, Yifu Lin became chief economist of the World Bank, the highest-ranking Chinese citizen yet to serve in that body. (All this is to be found in Evan Osnos’s excellent Age of Ambition: Chasing Fortune, Truth, and Faith in the New China, (Farrar, Straus, and Giroux, 2014.).

Lin was one of the very first movers in the epochal events that followed the third Plenum in December 1978. Millions followed, high and low, in accordance with Deng Xiaoping’s mantra, “Let some people get rich first.” By the end of the 20th Century, China was on the verge of becoming the second largest economy in the world. Average annual growth of 10 percent for 20 years had lifted half a billion people out of poverty and changed the lives of countless others around the world.

Entry of China into the world trading system was only one of those once-small clouds to have swiftly grown into all-encompassing developments in the ’90s and ’00s. The advent of the computer was another; financial deregulation after Mayday 1975 was a third. These are the changes we are concerned with here. Still others – gender convergence, for example – have only just begun to have their impact gauged.

Meanwhile, the cutting-edge economic theorists who had recently transformed macroeconomic policy-making by incorporating more psychologically-realistic agents in their models embarked on a new program. Again taking their cue from Robert Lucas, whose influential essay “Understanding Business Cycles” appeared in 1977, these “new classicals” would seek to devise a more satisfying explanation of the pattern of boom and bust that had characterized market economies for centuries.

Since the 1950s, business cycles had been understood mainly in Keynesian terms:  small models of loosely-described aggregates, consumption, investment, government spending, inflation and unemployment. These did well enough for short-term forecasting. They had moderated in the years since World War II, of course – economists now spoke of expansion and contractions, or recessions, instead of periods of prosperity and depression. But whatever their sources, alternating bouts of unacceptable levels of inflation and unemployment had become the central problem of economics.

Once economists had accepted the “rational expectations” postulate of forward looking, partially informed economic actors – and taken seriously Lucas’s critique of models that didn’t allow the actors they depict to take account of policy-makers’ intentions – those Keynesian models were useless for evaluating monetary and fiscal policies. Only process-oriented (“dynamic”) models based on the new mathematized understanding of general equilibrium would do.

Over the next 25  years, one candidate for the task seemed to succeed more than any other.  The theory of “real business cycles” produced reformulations sufficiently surprising that its enthusiasts routinely described it as “a scientific revolution.” These developments culminated in the award of Nobel Prize, in 2004, to Fynn Kydland, of the University of California at Santa Barbara, and Edward Prescott, then of the University of Minnesota. Within a decade, RBC theory was widely, but not universally, judged to have been discredited by the crisis of 2008.

This is the story of the 30-year boom, told against the backdrop of the development of “real business cycle” theory.  The  tools used to construct RBC theory were, in due course, employed to build models of other, quite different theories. The class to which they all belonged came to be described for the ambitions that all had in common – they were dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) models.  Today the field is simply “modern macro.”

The tale of the 3-0-year boom is not the usual one about Margaret Thatcher and Ronald Reagan, though the British prime minister and the American president are certainly part of it.  It’s a long story, having to do mostly with how the Practicals of the world got far ahead of its economic theorists. I am going to barely sketch it here. Once again, I reluctantly split in half on the Web what in a better world would be an integral chapter. But it is an important story, critical to understanding what happens next.

.                                       The Three Worlds

Let’s begin by returning to the realm of growth theory, meaning the history of the division of labor. A new chapter in global specialization and interdependence is clearly what the China story is about.

Readers of "Adam Smith, Theorist, '' the fourth episode in this serial, will remember the argument.  Smith’s Wealth of Nations contained not one but three “thinking caps,” or paradigms, as we call them now, There was price theory, as represented by the metaphor of the Invisible Hand; growth theory, conveyed by Smith’s disquisition on the pin factory; and monetary theory, symbolized by the metaphor of “Daedalean wings.”

Economists became preoccupied with price theory and left specialization and money to others.  Monetary theory remained inside the tent of economics, though in a junior place, with much of its work done by central banking practitioners; growth theory operated at the fringes of the tent, or , more commonly, outside of economics altogether: Charles Babbage, John Rae, Friedrich List, most famously Karl Marx, and his 20th Century epigone Joseph Schumpeter. John Stuart Mill smoothly effected the separation of specialization out of economics when he wrote, in 1848, in Principles of Political Economy:

"In so far as the economical condition of nations turns upon the state of physical knowledge, it is a subject for the physical sciences, and the arts found on them. But in so far as the causes are moral or psychological, dependent on institutions and social relations, or on the principles of human nature, their investigation belongs not to the physical but to moral and social science, and is the object of what is called Political Economy.''

For the next  80 years, as Germany and Japan industrialized, they learned economics from the British, French, Austrians and Scandinavians; economics learned measurement from the Germans.  The European powers raced to establish imperial dominion over portions of the Earth not previously claimed. What today we call “development economics” was mostly handled by students of Karl Marx. They took power in Russia, in 1917.

Then came the Great Depression.  John Maynard Keynes, though he had as a young man worked on Indian currency problems, was thoroughly Eurocentric.  Schumpeter, Hayek and Irving Fisher were hardly less so.  H.W. Arndt, of Oxford University, later summarized James Meade’s overview of “business activity” for the 1938 World Economic Survey of the League of Nations this way:

"Developments in the United States, Western Europe, and Japan, were covered in some detail in twenty-six pages; the “primary producing countries” (Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Argentina, Brazil, Chile; Hungary, Rumania, Yugoslavia) rated one paragraph and a table; the Balkans, the Dutch East Indies, one sentence each; South America, one paragraph; all the rest, including all of Asia (except Japan), Africa, and the USSR, were completely ignored.''

With the end of World War II approaching, U.S. President Franklin Roosevelt insisted that the European nations must give up their colonies. Decolonization eventually happened, by fits and starts. The climactic Chinese Revolution in 1949 accomplished the rest: the division of the world into three great blocs of nation-states – the so-called First World (the industrial market economies), a Second World (the communist nations), and a Third World of new countries in Africa and Asia, known as “less developed countries,” or LDCs.

These were the circumstances that obtained after 1945.  For the communist nations there would be central planning, a discipline known in the Soviet Union as mathematical cybernetics; for the Third World, development economics. Economists in the West would pursue the  “Keynesian Revolution. In the story I’ve been telling in this serial, that was only the beginning of “the New Economics.”

.                              Solow – Establishing the Trend

From the outset, Keynesian economists had been preoccupied with preventing the recurrence of massive, involuntary unemployment. Gradually it grew apparent that the industrial economies, the U.S. economy in particular, were more robust and stable than had been expected. By the early 1950s, the new National Income and Product Accounts made it clear that the U.S.  economy was growing more swiftly than others. How to account for national growth rates became one of the outstanding problems.

It fell to Robert Solow, of MIT, to sort out the issue.  He had inherited a pair of models constructed by two older Keynesians, one by Roy Harrod, from 1939; the other by Evsey Domar, from 1946.  Both depicted growth as a very fragile process, prone to runaway booms and interrupted by long depressions. That didn’t seem to be the case with the U.S.  economy in the post-war world.

A gifted craftsman in the new techniques of mathematical model-building, Solow solved the problem through the simple expedient of permitting substitution. In place of the fixed capital/output ratios of the earlier models, he adopted an equation known as a production function, one that allowed for substitution between capital and labor. He illustrated the relationship with a simple graph, relating changes in capital intensity to the savings rate. The model was sleek and simple and old-fashioned; just population growth, capital formation and productivity growth. It had little in common with the attempts to relate consumption and investment and government expenditure that dominated the Keynesian agenda of the ’50s.

The next year Solow tested it empirically, using U.S.  GNP data for the period 1909-1949. After he estimated the production function by which workers in factories turned capital investment in machinery into output, he found that he had only explained about 15 percent of the reported growth of output for those years.  Something like 85 percent of growth had to be imputed to the broad concept of technical progress.

This was “the Residual”—the portion of increased GDP unexplained by capital accumulation and population growth.  There now began a series of efforts to refine measurement, mostly through the then-new concept of human capital, meaning investment in education. None of this altered the basic finding very much at all.  New technology, including improvements in organization and the like, account for 60 or 70 percent of growth. .

Solow experimented with various improvements.  Gradually he returned to macroeconomics and, in particular, the Phillips Curve. For more than a decade, growth seemed to be a settled topic.  By the time that Solow received the Nobel Prize for his work, though, in 1987, Paul Romer, 32, had brought interest in growth back to a boil.

.                               Romer – opening things up

Romer had been, like Lucas, a University of Chicago undergraduate. Like Lucas, he had gone away to graduate school, before returning to Chicago to complete his graduate work: Lucas to the University of California at Berkeley, where he had studied history for a term with David Landes; Romer, to MIT where, after two years, he passed his economics field exams. After a year auditing courses at Queens University in Kingston, Ontario, while his wife completed her medical training, Romer returned to Chicago and wrote a dissertation supervised by José Scheinkman and Lucas.When he went on the job market in 1982, Solow and others sought to persuade him to return to MIT. He took a job teaching at the University of Rochester instead.

Romer’s dissertation appeared in 1986 as “Increasing Returns and Long Run Growth.” He had used the Arrow framework of contingent states, embedded in a model developed by Tjalling Koopmans and David Cass, to produce a dynamic account of the growth process.  It was close in spirit to the Solow model, but because consumption was decentralized.  Instead of being treated as a given, the savings rate thus became a matter of choice for actors within the model.  This meant that all manner of policies could influence the outcome.  The effect was electric: economists love to manipulate policy levers. Suddenly growth theory was booming again.

Tucked away in Rochester, Romer discovered a problem. He had set out to depict profit-seeking investment in research and development.  But there was no reason to undertake it in his model; the math he had employed wouldn’t let him do it: Every new bright  idea was instantly copied away before it could earn a return, through the magic of uncompensated “spillovers.” (I do a better job of telling this somewhat complicated story in Knowledge and the Wealth of Nations: A Story of Economic Discovery (Norton, 2006)).

So Romer turned to a bag of tools designed sixty years before to capture just such situations, the convention known as  monopolistic competition. He wrote temporary monopolists into his model – holders of trademarks, patents, copyrights, and, most of all, the slowly-wasting secrets we call know-how. Now he had an economy in which there was plenty of reason to invest in new products and new knowledge about how to make more.

But no longer did his model exhibit the kind of perfect competition associated with price system as governed by the Invisible Hand.  Now someone would have to make some rules governing  intellectual property. This was apostasy, at least in the Chicago tradition.  Then in January 1988, the University of Chicago hired him back as a full professor.

.                              Lucas – emphasizing education

When Romer returned to Chicago from MIT to write his dissertation in 1980, it didn’t take a genius to recognize that vast changes were occurring on the global stage.  Japan as Number One, by Ezra Vogel, was on best-seller lists. The economies of Singapore, Hong Kong, Taiwan and Korea were the “East Asian miracles,” The OPEC nations were spending heavily on infrastructure – and arms. Milton and Rose Friedman, who in their highly successful PBS television series Free to Choose had discussed Hong Kong, were invited to lecture in Beijing.  Paul Samuelson’s introductory text, which in its first edition, in 1948, mentioned the underdeveloped world precisely twice, and then only in passing, in its 1980 edition dwelt on the topic “from the front flyleaf to its chapter 5, ‘Income and Living Standards,’ to many of its last hundred pages,” as noted by H.W. Arndt in Economic Development: The History of an Idea.

Nevertheless, there was considerable excitement when Robert Lucas delivered his Marshall lectures at Cambridge, in 1984 and chose as his topic “The Mechanics of Economic Development.”  Lucas was already recognized in many quarters as the leading macroeconomist of the day; but the University of Cambridge, was not one of them. For 150 years the ancient English university had been the world capital of economics, but by now had been pretty decisively displaced by Cambridge, Mass., and Chicago. It was expected that Lucas would talk about rational expectations and monetary theory.

Instead, he asked to speak about growth.  It was a new field for him, he explained, but  he didn’t want to spend the second half of his career defending what he had done in the first. He didn’t say that recently, Edward Prescott, the friend and collaborator with whom Lucas had laboriously operationalized Arrow’s apparatus of contingent states, recently had begun a new program of research. Lucas had used the new tools of dynamic programming to put  the topic of money at the top of the profession’s docket. Now Prescott was using the same methods in an attempt to take it off again. Lucas decided to spar with Romer instead. The younger man’s work hadn’t been published yet, but the members of the Chicago department had been arguing among themselves about its significance for two years.

By assigning so great a role to “technology” as a source of growth, both Solow and Romer necessarily were assigning too small a role to alternative possibilities, Lucas argued.

"We say that Japan is technologically more advanced than China, or that Korea is undergoing unusually rapid technical change, and such statements seem to mean something (and I think they do). But they cannot mean that “the stock of useful knowledge” (in Simon Kuznets’s terminology) is higher in Japan or China, or that it is growing more rapidly in Korea than elsewhere. 'Human knowledge' is just human, not Japanese or Chinese or Korean. I think when we talk this way about differences in technology across countries, we are not talking about knowledge in general, but about the knowledge of particular people, or perhaps particular subcultures of people…. We want a formalism that leads us to think about individual decisions to acquire knowledge, and about the consequences for productivity. The body of theory that does this is called the theory of human capital….''

Already Romer was moving in the opposite direction, assigning still more importance to the economics of new goods and services. The formalism he was working on would lead economists to think about IBM, Microsoft, Google, Toyota, Samsung, and the Chinese Academy of Sciences. The excitement would spread. Economists studied Korean chaebol vs Japanese zaibatsu as engines of growth; the significance of banks; patents vs. prizes; the origins of the Industrial Revolution; the impact of various “general-purpose technologies” (steam, electricity, computers, the germ theory and public health); and, perhaps above all, the importance of trade.  The world was changing and economics was changing with it.

But the sparring with Lucas didn’t last for very long. After 18  months Romer quit his appointment at Chicago and in 1989 moved to California, where his physician wife enjoyed better employment opportunities. He spent a year at the Center for Advanced Studies in the Behavioral Sciences, at Stanford, taught for six years at the University of California at Berkeley, for 11  more at the Graduate School of Business at Stanford, where he won its distinguished teaching award prize in 1999, but he all but stopped publishing economic research. He founded a publishing company, quit Stanford to run it, sold it, and with the proceeds started a foundation to pursue the founding of  “charter cities” in empty spaces in developing nations, loosely based on the concept of charter schools. After two last-minute failures to launch, in Madagascar and Honduras, he is still looking for his first opening.

Romer returned to academia in 2010 as a professor at New York University’s Stern School of Business.  In January of this year he

launched an attack ondescribed at as Lucas’s tendency to “mathiness,” an accusation of bad faith which he has since refined in a series of blog posts. He may yet find ways to frame the issues better, but so far Romer’s campaign has mainly elicited curiosity.

.                               Prescott – maybe money doesn’t matter after all

Let’s go back to that Lucas essay, “Understanding Business Cycles,” in 1977. In the turbulence surrounding everything else Lucas was involved in — the success in reframing monetary theory, the new doctrine of policy ineffectiveness, the beginnings of “new growth theory – it  was easy to overlook what happened next.

Before Keynes, Lucas wrote, business cycles had been regarded as one of the main mysteries in all of economics; and incorporating cyclical fluctuations into general equilibrium theory, in which, in principle,they shouldn’t exist, one of its greatest challenges.  The Keynesian Revolution had redirected the effort to, as Lucas put it, “an apparently simpler question of the determination of output at a point in time, taking history as given.” Meanwhile, Keynesian macro had enjoyed the fruits of a second revolution (which, Lucas? said, owed more to the Dutch econometrician Jan Tinbergen than to Keynes)  in the level of precision and explicitness with which theories were formulated. Business-cycle theory had stagnated all the while.

"The economically literate public has had some forty years to become comfortable with two related ideas: that market economies are inherently subject to violent fluctuations which can only be eliminated by flexible and forceful government responses; and that economists are in possession of scientifically-tested knowledge enabling them to determine, at any time, what these responses should be.''

Never mind that public skepticism about economists’ pretensions had grown sharply in the 1970s. By now, Lucas said, the profession itself had doubts about the validity of the second proposition: it was ready to re-examine the first. The alternative possibility – the view that Lucas shared with Milton Friedman – was  that the economy was inherently fairly stable and that clumsy government policies undertaken to offset private-sector instability had been the root cause of the cycles over the years. Lucas wanted to put competing hypotheses to a test. But how?

Little noticed was the phrase with which Lucas had defined business cycles as “movements about trend in gross national product in any country…” This was a very different definition from that of the Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research. The NBER approach is a kind of statistical “thick description” that has evolved over nearly a century of comparing each new recession or expansions to the others. This agnostic index-building was condemned in 1947 as “measurement without theory” by the Cowles Commission, but it has endured, highly valued by those who believe that each bust probably is best understood in terms of the previous boom.

If not from the NBER, where to get a trend from which to discover the cycles to be explained?

In 1982, Edward Prescott, Lucas’s former collaborator, proposed a different way to build an apparatus with which to perform the tests that Lucas wanted.  With Fynn Kydland, his former student, he would take their trend from the neoclassical growth model – the Solow model, in the high-tech general equilibrium version fashioned by David Cass and Tjalling Koopmans.  They would derive their business cycles from that, using US quarterly data for the period 1950-1979. With his CMU colleague Robert Hodrick, Prescott produced a filter to remove the trend in order to leave the residual data – the cycles. With Kydland, he built a model that seemed to fit. Unemployment in the NBER version became “fluctuations in hours allocated to market activity that are too  large to be accounted for by changing marginal pructivities of labor as reflected in real wages.”

It turned out they didn’t need an unsteady hand on the money supply to explain the half-dozen post-war recessions Prescott and Kydland had identified, or even any  shock.  A constant series of small shocks would do.  Prescott called them “technology shocks.” He and Kydland  put investment dynamics at the heart of their model.  They called it Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations. The following year, inReal Business Cycles, John Long and Charles Plosser argued that money tends to simply track these ”variations in the real opportunities of the private economy,” rather than causing them. Economists since David Hume, including Friedman and Lucas, considered that money somehow played a vital role in business fluctuations.  Prescott’s argument was, on many levels, a surprising one.

This is no place to go into the intricacies of the new classical view of business cycles In the circles where high macroeconomic theory is done, RBC theory was the straw that stirred the drink after 1982, prompting myriad alternative systems to be created and propounded, gradually forcing the transition to the methodological style known as decentralized stochastic general equilibrium models.

Fortunately,Michel De Vroey, a professor of economics at the University of Louvain, has tracked the debates between the New Keynesians and New Classicals over the years, patiently and dispassionately. His book, A History of Economics: From Keynes to Lucas and Beyond (Cambridge, 2015), promises to be a landmark event in circles extending far beyond the history of thought into the controversies surrounding economics in the present day.  For an edifying foretaste, see "What Can Civil Society Expect from Academic Macroeconomics?''

Debates there were, though they remained recondite for the most part. Real Business Cycle Theory met resistance every step of the way from those who considered themselves practical, practicing macroeconomists. Lawrence Summers, of Harvard University, led the way in 1986 with "Some Skeptical Observations on Real Business Cycle History''.  N. Gregory Mankiw, also of Harvard University, in "Real Business Cycles: A New Keynesian Perspective,'' pointed out the irony that the theory appeared just as Federal Reserve chairman Paul Volcker demonstrated how powerful an effect monetary policy could have on prices, employment and output. Maurice Obstfeld and Kenneth Rogoff observed,  “A theory of business cycles that has nothing to say about the Great Depression is like a theory of earthquakes that explains only small tremors.”

But remember, this was the period that had been dubbed “the Great Moderation,”  In 2004, when the Nobel Prize was awarded to Prescott and Kydland, “for their contributions to dynamic macroeconomics: the time consistency of economic policy and the driving forces behind business cycles,” small tremors had been the rule for more than 60 years.

And so it was here that matters stood in 1982 – small clouds of discussion, in Cambridge, in Chicago, in Minneapolis-St. Paul, none bigger than a circle of a few academic economists – when the 25-year boom began.

.                                                              xxx

- See more at: http://www.economicprincipals.com/#sthash.1rfV3r2P.dpuf

David Warsh is proprietor of economicprincipals.com and a long-time economic historian and financial journalist.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Those deans of women

Deans of Women and the Feminist Movement, by Kelly C. Sartorius, Palgrave MacMillan Press (Historical Studies in Education) St. Martin’s Press, 2014. Remember when every coeducational college or university had a “Dean of Women”? It was a powerful and influential position, at least for the “coeds” under her charge (and it was always “her”). The dean of women was expected to provide guidance, protection and support for “coeds,” when women were a minority among undergraduates. How things have changed.

The position no longer really exists and perhaps with reason. Now that the majority of undergraduate students are women, unplanned pregnancy no longer is as big an impediment for women to completing college, marriage is less an expectation, and women have many more educational and professional opportunities than previously, one might consider the position of “Dean of Women” an anachronism, an historical artifact no longer needed.

Indeed, women are now university presidents, academic deans and widely integrated into post-secondary education at all levels. But not so long ago, that was far from the case.

Until the 1970s, a dean of women was one of the very few professional roles for women in administration in post-secondary education, indeed in nearly all aspects of higher education. To get there and make any sort of difference in the lives of her charges, she had to be fierce. And foresighted.

As Kelly C. Sartorius writes in Deans of Women and the Feminist Movement, this (woman’s) position sometimes challenged itself and its charges. Until the feminist movement began on coeducational college campuses in the 1970s, female college students had, in many respects, only deans of women to shelter and protect them, to act in loco parentis, and if they were lucky, help them become strong individuals.

While some of these deans provided career counseling aimed at making their charges able to support themselves financially, should the often-anticipated “Mrs.” degree not materialize, much of their work was directed at caretaking and maintenance of female college students. But there were deans of women who looked out rather than in, and this is where Sartorius focuses her book.

By taking a close look at the life and career of a very activist dean of women at Kansas State University, Emily Taylor, the author presents the case that this “women’s profession” foreshadowed, indeed shaped, contemporary circumstances in higher education for women. It’s an interesting perspective. Could a dean of women who was something of an early if unspoken feminist—along with her dean colleagues at other colleges and universities—prepare, even shape themselves, their institutions and their students for the enormous social and political changes, feminism and changing expectations of and for women in particular, that many now take for granted?

Kelly Sartorius is herself a good example of the influence of those activist deans of women such as Emily Taylor—women who worked within the establishment toward and with the deep and broad social changes that started only four decades ago. While working as a university administrator (in development), Sartorius earned a doctorate in history; this book is based on her dissertation.

The book itself is a nice combination of well-researched, thoughtful historical perspective, and interesting reading. (For example, how did public universities and their female students shape antiwar activism, racial issues and radical feminism?) More importantly, it is documentation of how the then-few professional women in higher education accommodated or, as Sartorius argues, enabled changes in higher education that expanded the personal, social and professional development of young women in college.

Times have changed. It remains important to be aware of how much that is the case and how it happened. This book is a good reminder.

Reviewed by Jane Sjogren O’Neil, an educator, economist and consultant. This piece originated on the Web site of the New England Board of Higher Education (nebhe.org).

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Grand old kitsch

Horton "Independence'' (archival pigment print), by NANCY GRACE HORTON, in  her ''Slyly Fractured'' show at the Trustman Art Gallery, at Simmons College, Boston, Sept. 2-Oct. 1.

Few people combine patriotic fervor  with kitsch  as  relentlessly as do Americans.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Robert Whitcomb: In the Amazon jungle

  amazon

Amazon is an impressive if rather creepy company, with its style set by its cold, “data-driven’’ founder/CEO, Jeff Bezos. An Aug. 15 New York Times piece, “Inside Amazon,’’ laid out the travails of the monopolistic and Darwinian enterprise’s white-collar workforce. Their issues have gotten more attention than the much worse Dickensian conditions of the blue-collar employees in its warehouses and the company’s relentless accumulation, like the also Orwellian Google’s, of our personal information. Amazonianism’s causes?

One is in the mirror. Americans have grown addicted to buying stuff online -- of course, the cheaper the better. They seem to want to avoid face-to-face interactions in stores -- and community engagement in general -- and Amazon’s power ensures that they’ll get low prices, at least for now (see below), even as their local stores close because of such online competition.

The preference for communicating via screens rather than person-to-person is especially common among the young, who grew up in the Internet Age. Human-resource managers have told me that young job applicants often don’t look them in the eye because in-person encounters make them anxious.

The disappearance of many well-paying jobs, and static (or worse) compensation except for top executives and investors, have encouraged consumers to seek out cheaper stuff than a few decades ago. But – irony of ironies! – Amazon and other high-tech automators have helped destroy good U.S. jobs in their “data-driven’’ mania to take full advantage of the international low-wage, cheap-goods machine.

Physical-store chains such as CVS and Home Depot are doing their bit to kill jobs --- by, for instance, installing automatic checkouts. I try to boycott stores with these machines because I know that each means the loss of another entry-level or second job for someone who needs it. This makes me feel better for a few minutes.

If Amazon’s workplace brutalities offend some consumers, they could resume shopping in their own communities and thus help employ some of their neighbors. Most won’t.

And look to Washington, where ideology and campaign contributions ensure that the Justice Department’s Antitrust Division doesn’t go after such monopolies as Amazon and Google. Until about 1980, Republican and Democratic administrations actually enforced laws against monopoly. The long disinclination to do so will hit consumers hard when Amazon, which has been undercutting other retailers to gain maximum market share, killing many brick-and-mortar competitors, suddenly jacks up prices big time.

Also consider the collapse of the private-sector union movement. If there were unions at Amazon, the Third World work environment would quickly go away. Gilded Age working conditions helped spawn the union movement in the first place. Now, management’s utter dominance has employees ready to put up with anything to keep their jobs.

Meanwhile, the “Big Data’’ revolution is turning workers into organic robots, soon to be replaced by real, inorganic robots. When every move of workers is measured for maximum productivity and profit potential, as at Amazon, kindly treatment of employees pretty much disappears. Employees are mere data points.

This process started with assembly-line and other blue-collar workers. The generally affluent types who read, say, The New York Times didn’t care that much. But turning employees into metrics is now heading rapidly up the food chain. Physicians, lawyers, tech engineers, middle managers and journalists (monitored for the number of Internet clicks their work gets) are being measured daily by senior executives who see their employees as entirely fungible and disposable.

And don’t expect the executive suite to share the riches from this speed-up with lower-level employees. The tendency for more and more of the wealth of companies to be shared by fewer and fewer people continues apace. We’re on a selfishness wave.

Amazon has created a fascinating machine for distributing goods. (Its delivery drones are next -- maybe equipped with surveillance gear?) Mike Daisey, writing in The Guardian (“Amazon’s brutal work culture will stay: bottom lines matter more than people,’’ Aug. 22), quoted comedian Louis C.K. as saying about such enterprises that “everything’s amazing and nobody’s happy’’ . Well, some are.

Anyway, most Americans seem to adore Amazon, which will repay them good and hard.

xxx

Lovely dim late-summer light today, and  leaves are falling off the plane trees from sheer exhaustion.

Robert Whitcomb (rwhitcomb51@gmail.com) is a  Providence-based editor and writer, a partner at Cambridge Management Group (cmg625.com) and a Fellow of the Pell Center, in Newport, He used to be the editorial-page editor of The Providence Journal, the finance editor of the International Herald Tribune and an editor at The Wall Street Journal, among other jobs.

 

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Dark and windy city

"Unquiet City XXA'' (pigment print on canvas) in the "Boston Through the Eyes of Robert Hesse Collection'' at the Patricia Ladd Carega Gallery, Center Sandwich, N.H.

I must admit that I have always found Boston unfriendly, class-ridden, too ethnically and religiously tribal and too windy. This picture reminds me of the chilling scenes outside my father's office on Federal Street in downtown Boston more than 50 years ago, when he worked for a long-dead Boston company called the United Shoe Machinery Corp. in a stepped, gold-topped Art Deco skyscraper put up right before the Depression. That slump lasted, off and on, into the '50s in Boston, at least in some ways. The Brink's Robbery was a nice distraction.

Poor John Cheever, the novelist and short-story writer who grew up just south of what we headline writers used to call "The Hub,'' used to get so depressed and anxious when he returned to Boston that he'd get drunk and sometimes be found like a bum sleeping on a bench in Boston Common.

Of course, he did have various "issues,'' as they say. But growing up in the downcast environment of Greater Boston was one of them.

The city is a lot spiffier now than it was a few decades ago, but no friendlier.

I'll take Manhattan., or even Brooklyn.

-- Robert Whitcomb

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Fleeing the Islamic world

Think of the many millions who would flee if they could the brutalities of  parts of Islamic society, which trap them in bigotry, cruelty, corruption, poverty and ignorance. But just look at how many thousands are fleeing, despite the perils involved. Review current migration and refugee maps. The migrations are almost entirely to the West, because the West is indeed best.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Chuck Collins: Our 'oligarchy with unlimited political bribery'

Is America’s political system controlled by a small financial elite? One former president thinks so.

Almost 40 years after he was elected, former President Jimmy Carter commented recently that our political system is now “an oligarchy with unlimited political bribery.” He may be right.

For the last three decades, wealth has concentrated in fewer and fewer hands. Just how few? As of 2013, the wealthiest 3 percent of households in the United States held more than half of all private wealth.

All that concentrated wealth translates into concentrated political muscle — including the power to influence elections.

As of this summer, over half of all donations to Republican super PACs came from just 130 wealthy families and their businesses. Democratic candidates had a wider base of small contributors, but also plenty of big-money donors of their own.

We’re now living through the billionaire primary. Six months before a single vote is cast in New Hampshire, the field of candidates is being selected and winnowed by billionaire donors.

Indeed, it seems like a presidential hopeful must have at least one billionaire backer — and ideally several — to be considered a credible candidate. Roofing billionaire Diane Hendricks gave $5 million to the Scott Walker campaign. Houston billionaire Toby Neugebauer gave a $10 million boost to Ted Cruz. Oracle CEO and billionaire Larry Ellison gave $3 million to Marco Rubio.

This political-patronage system effectively disenfranchises ordinary voters.

images-18.jpeg

Since the Supreme Court’s Citizens United decision opened the floodgates for unlimited political sending, the pace of contributions has only escalated. Super PACs have already raised $258 million for this election cycle — more than 16 times the total from this point in the 2012 race.

Unfortunately, this is just the tip of iceberg.

The wealthy are major contributors to a vast array of other lobbying groups masquerading as tax-exempt social welfare organizations. The Koch brothers alone have vowed to give and raise nearly $1 billion for these kinds of groups and related work by think tanks and universities during this electoral cycle.

These organizations don’t have to disclose the identity of their donors, even as they increasingly influence our elections.

The Federal Election Commission has effectively thrown up its hands in attempting to regulate this secret money. As a result, untold additional millions will flow through these tax-exempt corporations, providing the super-wealthy with another avenue to influence the outcome of state and federal elections.

This isn’t just a new Gilded Age. As Campaign Finance Institute President Michael Malbin says, this may even be a new “Platinum Age.”

What can we do?

Encouraging movements are forming in response to the corruption of our electoral system. So far, 70 former members of Congress have come together to form the bipartisan ReFormers Caucus to press for campaign finance reform. And a new group, 99Rise, has launched a campaign to expose and eliminate secret money from our campaign finance system.

Carter laments that the present system of campaign finance “violates the essence of what made America a great country in its political system.”

A century ago, Louis Brandeis expressed similar fears for our fragile experiment in self-governance. “We must make our choice,” the future Supreme Court justice said. “We may have democracy, or we may have wealth concentrated in the hands of a few, but we can’t have both.”

We must make our choice: democracy or rule by the rich?

Chuck Collins is a senior scholar at the Institute for Policy Studies (IPS-dc.org) and the co-author, with Bill Gates Sr., of  Wealth and Our Commonwealth: Why America Should Tax Accumulated Fortunes. This originated on OtherWords.org.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

We're all stereotypes

Briggs  

"Stephen, Coach/Educator'' (silver gelatin print), by KEVIN J. BRIGGS, in the show "Stereotypes: A Conscious Look at Race, Faith, Gender and Sexual Orientation,'' at Gallery Seven, in Maynard, Mass., through Sept. 26.

Mr. Briggs says that as an African-American, he  had a few episodes in his life that left him with an acute realization that he was sometimes not seen as a distinct individual but as a stereotype.

 

 

 

 

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Chris Powell: Well-run states shouldn't need to bribe to keep firms

  Back in June the leaders of the Democratic majority in the Connecticut General Assembly, having just passed another huge tax increase, including substantial business taxes, scoffed at complaints by major businesses, including General Electric, whose headquarters is in Fairfield. GE threatened to leave the state.

Senate President Martin Looney, D-New Haven, said GE was just using the tax increases as an excuse for layoffs it already planned. House Speaker Brendan Sharkey, D-Hamden, agreed, adding that GE was "fear mongering" and that tax policy couldn't be inducing the company to move. They noted that GE probably wasn't paying much in state corporation income taxes at the moment, but that was misleading. For GE's resentment seems to have been triggered by the state's change to a system of "unitary taxation," by which corporation earnings attributed to transactions out of state would be taxed here too.

Governor Malloy didn't scoff as his party's legislative leaders did. The governor took the business complaints seriously and persuaded the legislature to reconvene in special session to reduce and delay the tax increases. While this wasn't much, the governor long has been offering tax breaks and grants to induce businesses to locate or stay in the state, so he knew intimately that other states are doing the same thing and that most big businesses today have little loyalty to anything beyond money.

The other businesses that complained about the tax increases may have been mollified but not GE. There lately have been reports that the company is negotiating its relocation with Georgia and New York and that the Malloy administration is assembling a counter-offer. If GE pays little in state taxes now, it soon may pay even less.

GE most benefits the state economically not through corporate income taxes but through its huge employment, about 5,700 people here, and through the income, property, and sales taxes they pay. That would be a lot of jobs to lose.

But paying GE to stay would have its own costs. State government would be seen to have yielded to a major extortion and the other big companies that complained about "unitary taxation" and an ill-conceived tax on data processing would be tempted to try their own. Indeed, GE's extortion likely was encouraged by the extortion paid by state government last year to United Technologies Corp. for little more than the company's promise to keep its employment here steady while it expands elsewhere.

Smaller businesses, which don't have the same leverage, would be further demoralized by the unfairness of paying GE to stay, since, in effect, everybody else in Connecticut would be having his taxes increased just to keep GE and its employees happy.

This really isn't "economic development." Since it just shifts burdens from one set of businesses to another set, it's more like political patronage and corporate welfare, and it should stop.

For if Connecticut cannot attract and sustain business by virtue of its basic characteristics -- labor force skills, transportation and technological infrastructure, favorable taxation, efficiency of government, and general living conditions -- the state should work on those characteristics before it pays extortion. Surely those characteristics need much improvement.

For starters, if state government ever could regain control over government employee costs and stop its welfare system from perpetuating poverty through child neglect and abuse, it could easily forgo all revenue from big companies that might try extortion.

Imagine being able to tell GE and the world that Connecticut is so well-managed and attractive that it doesn't need to pay extortion. Of course,  that would require alienating the government employee unions and welfare recipients, child abusers and their coddlers. But there may be a reason why no states are bidding for them.

Chris Powell is managing editor of the Journal Inquirer, in Manchester, Conn.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Charles Pinning: The fungibility of fun and funds

  hay

(Photo by CHARLES PINNING)

Hay bales on a Little Compton, R.I., farm

One languorous August afternoon, my friend Peter Lapin phoned to tell me that a farmer near where he lived in Middletown, R.I., would pay us $120 apiece for a week of loading hay. My parents had been on my case for laying around all summer, so I agreed.

“Good luck,” scoffed my older brother, busy patching a ding on his surfboard. “Get ready to suffa. And on the way, watch out for the cow pies!”

“Yeah-yeah, blah-blah,” I responded.

“Gerbil,” he deadpanned. “Why do you think a stud like me is a lifeguard instead of working on Old MacDonald’s Farm? You’ll find out.”

Equipped with iron hooks and work gloves that were too big for us, we traipsed behind a lumbering stake body truck, wrestling bales of hay up onto the bed as it belched stinking black exhaust.

All week the sun blazed in a cloudless sky and the humidity soared. It was backbreaking work for two 13-year-old boys whose bodies hadn’t really developed yet. Our legs got scraped up and the inside of our forearms were scratched and welted. We were drenched in sweat, hair matted, eyes stinging, hay dust filtering down into our cut-offs.

At night, I spread Noxzema on my red cheeks and shoulders, doused my welts with witch hazel and swabbed my scrapes with clear merthiolate. After dinner I fell into bed, senseless and sore.

But come Friday afternoon, it was all over — the fields were clear, the hay was in the barn, and the farmer paid us $120 in cash, each.

“Hey,” said Peter, “Let’s go to the beach!”

We bicycled over to Easton’s Beach, threw down our bikes and raced across the hard sand into the water.

Heaven! The waves were good, the cool water balm to my scorched flesh. After bodysurfing a couple, I suddenly panicked. I jammed my hand into the pocket where I’d folded my money and it was gone. All $120 was gone!

I twisted hopelessly, searching the surface then staggered out of the water and flopped face down on the sand. I couldn’t say anything to Peter, who’d had the good sense to shove his money into a shoe. He would laugh, called me stupid, make me feel worse than I already did. When we bicycled home in our separate directions, tears streamed down my face.

I hid in my room until my mother came knocking.

“Clean up and come down for dinner. We’re celebrating with your favorite!”

“I’m not hungry,” I said in a low voice.

“What?”

“Nothing!” I shot back.

On the table was spaghetti and shrimp in a cream sauce.

“We’re really proud of you,” my father said. “You stuck it out on the hottest week all summer. Real bull-work under tough conditions. Congratulations.”

“Any plans for the money, sweetheart?” asked my mother.

“Just enjoy it, son,” said my father. “You’ve earned it. Have a good time with it. Why not take Anna out to a movie. I’m sure she’d like that.”

Anna was my next-door neighbor who’d moved in only a year ago. I would’ve loved to have taken her to a movie. She was the nicest girl I’d ever met, actually.

After dinner I went up to my room and curling into a ball, cried myself to sleep.

In the morning, I woke up to the horror that it hadn’t been a dream. I stayed in my room all day, doing my summer reading. I finally came down for dinner and was bumping my shoulder up against a doorway when my brother came whooping into the house.

“Dig it, gerbils: another big day for the stud!”

Strutting into the living room, he twirled once around. “Guess what the good news is?” he asked.

“You saved someone’s life!” said my mother expectantly.

“You decided to get a haircut,” said my father.

“Well, gerbil, what about you?”, he asked me.

“I have no idea, stud. You’re getting married.”

“Studs don’t get married, gerbil. I found a hundred bucks on the beach! No lie! Life is good!”

 Charles Pinning is a Providence novelist.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Where it's Arbor Day everyday; Kennedy on Chappy

dupont2 “Path, Arnold Arboretum” (photo), by RUSSELL duPONT, in the show "Artists in the Arboretum,'' at the Arnold Arboretum of Harvard University, 125 Arborway, Boston, Sept. 17-Oct. 18.

Arboretums can be magical. We just toured the exquisite and unexpected Mytoi Japanese Garden on Chappaquiddick Island, part of Martha's Vineyard. Very, very soothing. Everything was perfect except that otters had eaten all the gold fish in the lily-padded pond.

Then  we took on the ugly, as we traced the routes that the late Sen. Edward Kennedy took in his drinking, driving and other activities  on the night of July 18, 1969 that resulted in the death of Mary Jo Kopechne when Mr. Kennedy drove a car off a bridge into the water.

None of excuses/explanations he gave were plausible but local authorities were in the pocket of the Kennedys so he avoided a vehicular-manslaughter charge and proceeded with his political career. But the accident may well have prevented him from becoming president.

-- Robert Whitcomb

 

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Yankee hills

wolf "Mountain Ridge'' ( watercolor and charcoal), by SALLIE WOLF, at Patricia Ladd Carega Gallery, Center Sandwich, N.H.

I find that  after years of driving through the low mountains west-northwest of Concord, N.H., this is the most accurate image of that semi-wild countryside.

--- Robert Whitcomb

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Anders Corr/Kyoko Sato: Dreamy scapes of oil paint

anderspic “Summer Winds”  (oil on canvas, 1984), by  RYOICHI MIURA. Courtesy of Kamakura Shirts Collection, Kanagawa, Japan.

A boy sits on a miniscule tatami (a mat) on the second floor of a miniature house, gazing at the Pacific Ocean. A kitten sleeps on a pillow. Sounds of waves and wind chimes wash over a bicycle and tobacco box obscured by shadow on the ground floor. It’s a summer day in Japan.

The self-taught painter Ryoichi Miura (b. Japan 1956-) dreamed, in black and white, the scene painted in “Summer Winds”. He met us last week at the Harvard Club of New York City and over a summertime special of chilled avocado soup recounted his inspiration for the painting. “I wanted to color the scene. It was so unique to me because I had never seen a monochrome dream”. He just closed the show “Summer: Gallery and Invited Artists” (July 28-Aug. 15) at the Prince Street Gallery in New York.

A dreamy, deformé style epitomizes Ryoichi’s paintings. His signature and contemporary aesthetic is rooted in Garo, a monthly manga (comics) magazine (Seirindo, Japan, 1964-2002). “A big brother of my friend showed me the issue of July 1968 when I visited their home. I saw Ernest Hemingway’s The Killers, a comic {book} by Maki Sasaki. I was totally shocked and I could not move at all!”

Miura immediately asked his mother to subscribe to the magazine. When the bookstore hand-delivered his first issue, as was the norm in the 1960s, Miura jumped from the bathtub and ran dripping, merely covered by a towel, to receive it from the delivery man.

Ryoichi became an artist from that point. He drew his first manga, and brought it to school. His teacher read it aloud in the classroom. He still feels pride that everyone in the classroom, including his teacher, admired the art. Miura painted his first oil painting when he was 13, and has painted ever since. One of his earliest paintings still hangs in the principal’s room of his junior high school, Miura proudly recounts, 46 years later. Miura is now 59.

The earliest influence from manga is delightfully visible in his current art. Illustrations in his children’s book, Kids in N.Y. (Kaiseisha, Japan, 2003), are eerily angled, imbalanced, falling. “New York City is always moving. I wanted to express its movement and speed of the city.”

Miura is the Edward Hopper (American, 1882-1967) of his moment in New York City. Like Hopper, Miura’s paintings are lonely, urban, stark, transitory, estranged, anxious and tightly cropped. Yet Miura is hotter, faster, and more emotional.

Miura, above all, wants to communicate emotion. “I see a scene that gives me an emotional response,” he said. “I want the viewers of my paintings to feel this moment of emotion, the color, the movement.” His medium is important to his message. “I can express it [emotion, color, and movement] only because I am using oil, not camera.” Only with oil and the texture of paint, for example, does he believe that he could paint the smile of a woman, what became his favorite painting, in vermillion red. He says he will never be able to paint such a piece again, and has refused to sell it to buyers.

Ms. Tamiko Sadasue purchased “Summer Winds” in 2013 at the Prince Street Gallery because it symbolizes old Japan – a simpler time after World War II when she was a young girl and Japan had a dream. The painting hangs in Kanagawa Japan at the head office of her company, Kamakura Shirts, as a symbol of Japan’s dream of a prosperous future linked to a simpler, Hopperesque past.

While other artists chase new media, Miura sees value in the classical medium of oil. “I need to wait for 2 weeks for drying, always takes long, need to make tremendous efforts to finish a work. That is valuable for me, especially because we are living in such a convenient world,” says Miura. “I have many more objects and themes I want to paint. Through my paintings, I would like to show my own worlds with my own colors and textures to the people.“

Miura’s dream of painting color into the black and white, proceeds apace with the speed of New York City.

Anders Corr, Ph.D., founded Corr Analytics in 2013. Ms. Kyoko Sato is a curator in New York City.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Llewellyn King: 'Project ghosts' leave engineers demoralized

We need more engineers. Go forth and study engineering for the future of the nation. Math and engineering are the keys to maintaining our place in the world and keeping the Chinese, and a few others, at bay. That is the urging of our political class, whether they are appointed public officials or elected politicians; or whether they are members of the thinking and writing class. Taken collectively, they might be called “the exhortationists.”

But there is a problem: We do not treat engineers very nicely — at least not those who are federal employees or contractors. The very politicians who lead in exhorting our young to become engineers are those who treat engineers as disposable workers.

The government starts many projects and finishes few. A change of administration, a shortage of money, or some other excuse and the government shelves the project.

The impact on engineers is devastating. They have often relocated their families to the site of the project and — wham! — it is canceled.

It is not only that this rough treatment has a huge impact on families – and engineers are not that well-paid (median income is $80,000, and petroleum engineers are the highest-paid) – but also the psychological damage is considerable.

Engineering a new project is exciting but also demanding. Men and women throw themselves into what is a giant creative undertaking, eating up years of lives, demanding the most extreme effort. It is shattering when there is a sudden political decision to cancel a project.

To look at a bridge or a locomotive and say, “I built that,” “I made a difference,” is much of the engineer’s reward. Marc Goldsmith, a fourth-generation engineer, who has worked on 16 projects in nuclear power  that have been canceled, says that many engineers get so frustrated they leave the profession and go into law or finance, and never face a logarithm again. He says the government treats highly educated engineers like day laborers: expendable.

Goldsmith, a former president of the American Society of Mechanical Engineers, says the heartbreak of a canceled project to the engineers is terrible and destructive of the can-do engineering culture.

The hundreds of engineers involved in a big engineering project do not do their job just for the money, but for the satisfaction that they solved a problem and made a thing that worked, whether it was a mega-passenger aircraft, a spindly skyscraper or a flood-control gate.

We now live in a world of project ghosts, where public policy (politics) has said “go,” and has said later, with the same passion, “abandon.”

Clarence L. “Kelly” Johnson, the genius founder of the Lockheed secret division of engineers, dubbed Skunk Works, in Burbank, Calif., told me before he died in 1990 that some of the starts-and-stops and abrupt cancellations of military projects made him sick. The Skunk Works, which brought us such legends as the U-2 and the SR-71, to name a few, was also instructed by the government to eradicate any trace of other projects that were far along. “Not only were they canceled, but they had to be expunged,” he told me.

Nuclear has been especially hard hit by government policy perfidy. In today’s shame roster, Yucca Mountain, the nuclear waste repository and the pride of thousands of engineers, was abandoned by the incoming Obama administration in a deal with Harry Reid, the Democratic senator from Nevada and Senate majority leader. Good-bye to $15 billion in taxpayer money; good-bye to a nuclear waste option; and goodbye to all that intricate engineering inside a mountain.

Now the administration is taking its policy sledgehammer to another engineering project: one it supported until it didn’t support it anymore. It is trying to end the program to build a plant to blend surplus weapons-grade plutonium with uranium and burn it up in reactors as uranium oxide, or MOX, as it is known.

The contractor – a consortium of Chicago Bridge & Iron Co,  and Areva, the French firm – says the plant is 67-percent complete and employs 300 engineers, out of a total workforce of some 1,800, at the Department of Energy site near Aiken, S.C. Now this big engineering project, which is another way of dealing with nuclear waste, is in the government’s sights.

Llewellyn King (lking@kingpublishing.com) is executive producer and host of White House Chronicle, on PBS. This oroiginated on InsideSources.com.

Read More
Commentary Robert Whitcomb Commentary Robert Whitcomb

Chris Powell: Declining civic engagement imperils community hospitals

  Having decided that it can't sustain itself financially, Eastern Connecticut Health Network, operator of Manchester Memorial and Rockville General hospitals, continues to try to find a buyer. The latest bidder is Prospect Medical Holdings, Tenet Healthcare Corp. having withdrawn last year when state government imposed onerous conditions on its bid.

ECHN President Peter Karl says the company has to cut expenses by 15 to 20 percent, and the communities it serves have an interest in knowing how this would be accomplished, especially since one option would be to close Rockville.

Two recent public hearings called by ECHN and Prospect provided little useful information. While Prospect said it planned to keep nearly all ECHN employees, honor union contracts, and maintain Rockville, it would not respond to the  Journal Inquirer's {of Manchester, Conn.} questions about how it might exact savings from ECHN's operations.

Maybe some hints will be obtained from Prospect by the state attorney general's office and health department, which will supervise the sale of ECHN and have asked Prospect for answers on about 50 issues.

Even so, Prospect is not likely to offer any long-term guarantees. Its plans will be good only until they change, and medicine is changing fast, in part because of government's increasing interventions, largely matters of shifting and concealing costs.

Part of that cost shifting and concealment will be the annual property tax revenue Manchester and Vernon expect to receive upon conversion of ECHN's hospitals from nonprofit to profit-making status, revenue estimated at $4.4 million. That windfall will be generated by increasing hospital charges to insurers and patients, reducing compensation to hospital employees, or exacting efficiencies in hospital operations, efficiencies that Prospect declines to identify.

Since towns never reduce property taxes and since most of their spending goes to unionized town employees who by contract receive salary and benefit increases every year, this cost shifting will transfer money from hospital patients and maybe hospital employees to town employees, cost shifting that will be essentially a tax on illness. Not one person in a thousand will be able to figure it out and instead the blame will fall falsely on medical insurers.

Every business operation can be more efficient. For example, it's not clear why ECHN's top executives should continue to be so highly paid while the company operates at such a loss. Having already negotiated two sales agreements, first with Tenet and now with Prospect, ECHN's management must have pretty good ideas of where cuts could be made, just as Prospect's management does, having bid for a money-losing company.

But even if state government pries some of these ideas out of Prospect and they cause controversy, what is the alternative to the sale of ECHN? Maintaining the hospitals as nonprofit, locally focused operations and deciding on and implementing the necessary efficiencies on the basis of community interest and participation would be possible only with much civic engagement, and that no longer seems available.

ECHN's board of trustees long has been compromised by self-dealing and conflicts of interest, some of its members receiving large payments from the company, and the company's 232 corporators -- the company's ultimate authority -- members of the communities served by ECHN, have been indifferent to this and to the board's long failure to get expenses under control. Indeed, last month when the corporators approved the sale of the company to Prospect, 27 percent of them didn't even vote. Why have they been purporting to serve as corporators?

As civic engagement declines, only  profit will be left to run hospitals and all sorts of  other things that once were run in pursuit of the public interest. It will be a very different world.

Chris Powell is managing editor of the Journal Inquirer, in Manchester, Conn.

Read More